We often hear that we, in United States, spend more on
healthcare than other high-income countries, but get less for our money. A
report from the Commonweath Fund, “Mirror,
Mirror 2017”, is among many pieces of research to reach that
conclusion. Just why is U.S. healthcare
spending so high and performance so low? What are the realistic options for
reformers? One of the report’s key charts provides an excellent framework for
discussing what it calls “flaws and opportunities for better U.S. healthcare.”
Why is U.S.
healthcare spending so high?
To understand why U.S. healthcare spending is so high, we can
begin by asking, , “High relative to what?” After all, as one of the wealthiest
countries in the world, we spend more than others on a lot of things. The
question is whether U.S. healthcare spending is higher than we would expect it
to be even when we take our generally high standard of living into account.
Consider, for example, the following scatterplot of
healthcare expenditures (HEX) per capita against GDP per capita. The eleven
countries covered in the Commonwealth report are shown in red and other OECD
countries in blue.* The United States is the furthest outlier in the chart,
falling more than four standard errors above the trend line. That puts it well
outside an interval of plus or minus two standard errors, which would be
expected to contain 95 percent of countries.
However, GDP may not be the appropriate basis of comparison.
According to the anonymous author of the blog Random Critical Analysis (whom I identify
hereafter as RCA), it makes more sense to compare healthcare spending, not to
GDP, but to a less familiar measure of living standards known as actual individual consumption
(AIC).
AIC is the sum of household final consumption expenditure,
final consumption expenditure of non-profit institutions serving households,
and government expenditure on individually consumed goods and services.
Government spending on healthcare, education, housing, and other goods and
services is included in AIC because those items are consumed individually by
consumers. However, spending that serves the public in general, such as
national defense and police protection, is not included. As a measure of a
country’s average standard of living, AIC is thus not sensitive to differences
among countries in the way healthcare funding is divided between public and private
sources.
The share of AIC in GDP varies widely within the OECD,
ranging from 59 percent in Norway to 78 percent in Greece. At 73 percent, the
U.S. ratio of AIC to GDP is near the top of that range. One reason that AIC varies
is that households in some countries consume more of their personal income and
save less. Trade deficits and surpluses are another reason. Since countries with
deficits import more than they export, they can use the extra imports to support
higher levels of both private and government consumption expenditures per
dollar of GDP. Both low saving and persistent trade deficits tend to raise the
share of AIC in GDP for the United States. It has the highest standard of
living in the OECD as measured by AIC, even though it does not have the highest
GDP per capita.
Not surprisingly, healthcare spending tends to increase as
AIC increases. Not only that, but
healthcare is a superior good, meaning
that its share of total spending increases as AIC grows. My estimate for OECD
countries is that each 1 percent increase in AIC is associated with
approximately a 1.6 percent increase in HEX. RCA gets similar results both
across countries and over time within individual countries. In the following
chart, which uses log scales on both axes, about 80 percent of the variability
in health expenditure is statistically explained by variations in AIC.**
Comparing this chart with the previous one shows that the
United States, although still an outlier in healthcare spending relative to its
OECD peers, is much less of one. When compared to AIC rather than GDP, U.S.
healthcare spending lies just 1.5 standard errors above its predicted level,
instead of 4 standard errors. That puts it well inside a 95 percent prediction
interval.
For completeness, it is worth noting that the preceding
chart says nothing about whether prices or quantities of healthcare are more
important in producing higher-than-expected U.S. healthcare spending. That
remains a matter of ongoing debate among healthcare economists.
One line of thought is reflected in a widely-cited paper with
the provocative title, “It’s the Prices, Stupid.” Anecdotal evidence,
such as $100 saline bags and million-dollar cancer pills, reinforces the
idea that excess healthcare spending stems from unreasonably high healthcare
prices.
However, there is also evidence pointing the other way. For
example, in another post, RCA argues that high U.S.
healthcare prices are partly explained by the so-called Baumol effect,
according to which productivity increases faster in goods-producing sectors
than in services as GDP rises. That causes wages and prices in service sectors,
including healthcare, to rise relative to the average price level as an
economy’s general standard of living increases. Corrected for the Baumol
effect, U.S. healthcare prices are not as far out of line with average OECD
prices as they would otherwise appear. RCA also cites direct evidence that
quantities have increased, along with total spending. (For anecdotal evidence
to that effect, see my own recent notes on dermatology clinics and urine drug testing.)
Whichever point of view one takes on the relative role of prices
vs. quantities, however, the point stands that high spending can only in part
be viewed as a “flaw” in our healthcare system. Yes, lack of competition,
perverse incentives, and misguided or ineffective regulations undoubtedly are
sources of inefficiency, but there are also more fundamental forces at work. On
the demand side, there is strong evidence, over time and across a wide variety
of national systems, that people are willing to devote an increasing share of
their total consumption spending to healthcare as their standard of living
rises. At the same time, the Baumol effect makes it inevitable that the price
of personal services, including healthcare services, will rise as standards of
living rise. Perhaps the real question, then, is not why we spend so much, but
why we get such poor performance in return.
Why is U.S.
healthcare performance so poor?
Health system performance, in the Commonwealth report,
represents a weighted average of scores on many individual variables. These are
grouped in into five categories: The care process, access, equity, healthcare
outcomes, and administrative efficiency. The following is a brief summary of
the findings in each category. A set of appendixes to the report provide full
data on each of the underlying variables for each of the eleven countries.
It turns out that the United States does rather well,
ranking fifth overall, in terms of the first category, “care process.” The
rankings are based on data covering preventative care, safety, coordination,
and engagement with patient preferences. Certainly, there are places where
there is room for improvement, but this is not the area of the rankings where U.S.
reformers should look for dramatic gains.
Instead, low U.S. performance scores can, to a much larger
degree, be traced to last-place rankings for healthcare access and equity.
Americans who lack insurance or face high out-of-pocket costs are far more
likely than citizens of the other countries to report skipped checkups and
serious problems paying medical bills, and are less likely to have a regular
doctor or clinic. What is more, the gap between access to healthcare by those
with below-average and above-average incomes is wider for the United States
than for any other country in the Commonwealth study.
The United States also ranks last among the eleven countries
in terms of healthcare outcomes. Broad measures of population health, including
infant mortality, life expectancy, and the prevalence of chronic diseases in
working-age adults are all worse in the United States than in any of the ten
other countries in the Commonwealth study. U.S. amenable mortality rates are
also much higher, and have been declining more slowly than elsewhere. (Amenable mortality is defined as
premature deaths that could potentially be avoided given timely treatment.)
The difference in healthcare outcomes appears to be linked,
at least in part, to problems in access and equity. That is suggested by the
fact that on variables that measure outcomes for people who actually receive
treatment for conditions like stroke, heart attacks, and cancer, U.S.
performance is well above average. Not everyone has access to the best
treatment, however, nor do people without insurance or with high out-of-pocket
costs always follow through on treatment that is offered.
Still, it would be wrong to attribute poor U.S. health
outcomes entirely to flaws in policy. Socioeconomic factors, such as obesity
and lack of exercise, also contribute. One study
found that traffic accidents, gun violence, and drug use account for as much as
two-thirds of the mortality gap between the United States and countries such as
Austria, Denmark, Finland, and Germany.
Administrative costs are the final performance category in
the Commonwealth report. This is an area in which many American advocates of a
single-payer system have high hopes for improving performance. They are right
to point out that the U.S. ranks poorly in this area compared to the median for
the Commonwealth study. However, even some European healthcare systems that
have higher overall performance scores struggle with some aspects of administrative
costs. In France (which is the worst-performing of the eleven in terms of
administrative costs), and also in Switzerland, Germany, and the Netherlands (all
with below-average scores), complaints about excessive time spent on insurance,
paperwork, and reporting are common. The United States is perhaps less of an
outlier in this area than one might think.
Implications for
reformers
Our review of the reasons for high U.S. healthcare spending
and low health system performance has clear implications for reformers, as
suggested by the following modification of the Commonwealth chart:
- There are limits on what U.S. healthcare reformers can reasonably expect to achieve in terms of spending and performance. Those limits are represented here as a “policy option envelope,” which is pushed to the right, relative to other countries, by high U.S. levels of actual individual consumption, and downward by socioeconomic factors. As a result, it cuts to the right and below the positions occupied by other countries in the sample.
- It is wishful thinking to hope that simply copying one of the various systems used in Australia, the UK, the Netherlands, or elsewhere would automatically produce similar results in terms of cost and performance. There is no easy path—probably no path at all—by which the U.S. could leap into the central cluster of low-cost, high-performing countries in the chart. That does not mean we have nothing to learn from others. It simply means that what works well elsewhere is likely to cost more here, or produce less favorable results, or both.
- Although we could certainly improve overall healthcare performance by prioritizing greater access to the system we now have, doing so would, other things being equal, mean an increase in spending.
- We could, instead, prioritize spending cuts to Medicaid, Medicare, ACA subsides, and other programs, but doing so would worsen performance. That is especially true when performance is measured as it is by the Commonwealth study, where large weights assigned to access and equity.
In listing these implications, I do not mean in any way to pour
cold water on reform efforts. Rather, I think that greater realism makes it
more important, and perhaps also easier, for reformers of all political
persuasions to work together.
In particular, I would emphasize that we are far from being tight up against the performance-vs.-spending tradeoff represented by the policy option envelope in the chart. There are many potential efficiency-enhancing initiatives, for which it ought to be possible to get broad consensus, that would move us closer to the curve. Those include measures to mitigate perverse incentives that encourage patients to seek and providers to offer care that is neither clinically nor economically effective. They would also include reforms designed to increase competition, improve price transparency, better educate consumers, and push back against socioeconomic factors that undermine public health.
In particular, I would emphasize that we are far from being tight up against the performance-vs.-spending tradeoff represented by the policy option envelope in the chart. There are many potential efficiency-enhancing initiatives, for which it ought to be possible to get broad consensus, that would move us closer to the curve. Those include measures to mitigate perverse incentives that encourage patients to seek and providers to offer care that is neither clinically nor economically effective. They would also include reforms designed to increase competition, improve price transparency, better educate consumers, and push back against socioeconomic factors that undermine public health.
None of these should be controversial in principle, although
many of them will meet resistance from special interests who profit from
existing inefficiencies. As Uwe
Reinhardt once put it, “Every dollar of health spending is someone else’s
healthcare income, including waste, fraud, and abuse.”
Still, even with maximum efforts to enhance efficiency, we need
to accept that healthcare will continue to consume a large share of both personal
and government spending. In the end, the prospect of continued high healthcare
spending is not a reason to resist reform, but rather, to do our best to make
sure that we get a good return on what we do spend.
Reposted from NiskanenCenter.org
Reposted from NiskanenCenter.org
_________________________________
*The chart covers 34 OECD countries, excluding
Luxembourg. Luxembourg is unusual in that nearly half of its labor force
commutes daily from neighboring EU countries. The commuters contribute to
Luxembourg’s measured GDP, but are not counted in its population. Moreover,
most of them get their healthcare where they live, not where they work. For
that reason, data on GDP per capita and health expenditures per capita for
Luxembourg are not comparable to those of other OECD countries. In our chart,
Luxembourg would be an extreme outlier in the lower-right hand corner.
Including it would pull the trend line down and exaggerate the degree to which
the United States is an outlier in the upward direction.
**One technical detail: Healthcare itself accounts for a
substantial share of all consumption spending, so as a matter of simple
arithmetic, HEX would increase as AIC increased even if healthcare spending
were completely uncorrelated with consumption spending on other goods and
services. To avoid bias, then, the scatterplot puts non-healthcare consumption
spending (AIC minus HEX) on the horizontal axis, rather than total AIC. For a
regression of HEX on AIC-HEX, the coefficient of determination (R2) is
0.80. As expected, that is a little less than the R2 of 0.87 obtained
when total AIC is used as the independent variable.
In part, some of these costs are the costs of advancement, but we may be past the time of encouraging advancement by throwing money at it, and reaching the point where managing advancement through quasi public institutions may be justified. If we continue to write blank checks for rents, those rents should be taxed at least.
ReplyDelete