The impacts of climate change are visible everywhere — wildfires in California, preseason hurricanes in the Caribbean, insufficient water in the Panama Canal, populations on the move everywhere from North Africa to Central America. Inflationary shocks are another looming worry. Food prices will become increasingly volatile, while property insurance rates will escalate — or insurance simply won’t be available. Labor costs will rise as employers spend to shield workers from hotter weather or raise wages where workers balk at heat exposure.
It all points not only to more inflation, but also to
greater variation and less predictability across sectors and regions. In fact,
that’s already happening. The figure below uses data from the Atlanta Fed to divide prices into half
that are “sticky” in the sense that they rarely change and half that are
“flexible,” meaning they go up or down with every bump to supply or demand.
Since the late 1990s, the volatility of flexible prices has exceeded that of
the “great inflation” of the 1970s. Even sticky prices are showing some ominous
wiggles.
In the years ahead, more volatile inflation will make it harder for the world’s central banks, America’s own Federal Reserve Bank included, to meet their commitments to stabilize prices. Will they be up to the job? Not without some changes in strategy.
How Central Banks Fight Inflation
The most common strategy for stabilizing prices among
central banks today is “inflation targeting.” The central bank of New Zealand
was the first to try it back in 1990. Now it is the official policy of the U.S.
Fed, the European Central Bank and many others.
The basic concept is simple. A central bank watches
forecasts of inflation for the coming year. If the expected rate of inflation
is higher than acceptable, the bank raises short-term interest rates. Those
feed through to longer-term rates, which, in turn, slow business investment and
consumer spending on homes, cars and other durable goods. If the forecast
inflation rate is “too low” — we’ll get to what that means in a moment — the
central bank cuts rates.
But policymakers must get the details right to make
inflation targeting work well. Here are three not-so-fine points that will loom
in a world of climate-driven volatility.
Setting the right target rate. When you first think
about it, you might suppose that if inflation is bad, the best target would be
zero percent — no inflation at all. In the early days, some highly respected
central bankers including Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan did advocate a zero target. But today, major central banks
set a target higher than zero, typically 2 percent, or a target
range centered on a rate higher than zero.
One reason for adopting a non-zero target is the need for
room to cut interest rates in recessions. In the U.S., for example, the Fed
estimates that to stimulate the economy, it has to push interest rates below
a “neutral rate” estimated to be about 0.6 percent higher than
the prevailing rate of inflation. If inflation is currently 2 percent, for
example, effective stimulus would require an interest rate lower than 2.6
percent.
Two percent is not sacred. Roger Douglas, who was finance
minister of New Zealand when that country first tried inflation targeting,is
reported to have said, “I just announced it was gonna be 2 percent, and it sort
of stuck.”
The lowest possible setting lies in a range from 0 to 0.25
percent. A cut in the policy interest rate from a neutral 2.6 percent to 0.25
percent would provide a quite a bit of stimulus. However, if the initial
inflation rate were zero, putting the neutral rate at 0.6 percent, there would
be almost no room for stimulus. Any recession would be likely to last longer
and the recovery from it would be slower.
A second reason for a positive target rate is to give more
room for relative prices and wages to adjust on their own. Even when the
economy is cruising along at full employment, differing trends in productivity,
consumer tastes and world trade are always pushing some prices and wages up and
others down.
Some welcome those relative changes and others resist them.
The strongest pushback comes from workers in lagging sectors, who resist wage
cuts. If they are unionized, they may strike. Even nonunion employers may find
that their best workers quit in the face of wage cuts, while the demoralized
remainder become less productive. Cutting prices in the face of falling demand
is not resisted as tenaciously as cutting wages, but many firms succumb only
under the extreme pressure of tanking sales.
A positive inflation target provides a cushion against these
downward wage and price rigidities. A 2 percent inflation target would permit
wage and price increases of 3 or 4 percent in leading sectors while still
allowing increases of 1 percent, or at least no outright cuts, in lagging
sectors.
But 2 percent is not sacred. Roger Douglas, who was finance
minister of New Zealand when that country first tried inflation
targeting, is reported to have said, “I just announced it was
gonna be 2 percent, and it sort of stuck.” Today, many economists think a target
higher than 2 percent would be appropriate, in part because it would
give central banks more room to cut rates in future recessions. The prospect
that climate change will increase price volatility only makes the logic of a
higher target that much more persuasive.
Targeting the right index. The next devilish detail is
which of many inflation indexes to use as the target benchmark. In the U.S.,
the one that makes the headlines is the consumer price index, or CPI. The
headline rate for the EU, the “harmonized index of consumer prices,” is
slightly different. The Fed sets its target in terms of a third measure, the
personal consumption expenditures index (PCE). Inflation benchmarked by the PCE
tends to run about half a percentage point below the CPI.
But the PCE index is not the only measure of inflation that
the Fed uses. It also pays close attention to “core inflation” — that is, PCE
inflation calculated excluding food and energy. The thinking is that this core
index gives a good picture of underlying inflation trends.
Adapting inflation targeting to climate trends is likely to
require raising the target rate itself, modifying the indexes used for
short-term policy decisions and lengthening the period over which inflation is
brought back to the long-term target after temporary shocks.
Monetary policy can control overall inflation in the long
run, but it can do little to affect relative price movements, such as isolated
spikes in, say, beef or gasoline prices. Overreacting to such transitory shocks
could easily backfire in a way that destabilized the economy.
Note that climate change could make current measures of core
inflation obsolete. Rather than moving randomly up and down from a stable
average, future food prices are likely to develop an upward trend relative to
less climate-sensitive goods. The same could be true of energy prices. In that
case, excluding food and energy from the target index would no longer make
sense.
One remedy would be to switch short-term targeting to a
“trimmed mean” index. Instead of arbitrarily treating food and energy as the
transitory factors, trimmed mean indexes simply clip off whatever prices are in
fact the most volatile in any given period. The Cleveland Fed already publishes a trimmed mean version
of the CPI and the Dallas Fed publishes a trimmed mean PCE.
And did I mention the multivariate core trend inflation index from the New
York Fed? Maybe I shouldn’t, or you’ll stop reading…
Lengthening the time horizon. Central banks do not try
to hold the rate of inflation at its target month by month. In fact, trying to
control inflation over a very short time horizon would risk harm to the real
economy by pressing too hard against price and wage rigidities. Accordingly,
without locking themselves into a strict calendar interval, central bankers use
language like “medium term” or “longer term” to suggest a time horizon of more
than a year but no more than a few years. If climate change intensifies the
volatility of inflation and turns previously transitory movements of food
prices into long-term trends, there would be a case for lengthening the time
horizon over which inflation is averaged out.
Taking all these adjustments together, then, adapting
inflation targeting to climate trends is likely to require a combination of
raising the target rate itself, modifying the indexes used for short-term
policy decisions and lengthening the period over which inflation is brought
back to the long-term target after temporary shocks.
Beyond Inflation Targeting
Inflation targeting, although common, is not universal. It
is worth looking briefly at the problems faced by the central banks of a
different group of countries — those that either have no separate currency of
their own or maintain fixed exchange rates pegged to the value of another
currency. Examples of countries with shared currencies include Ecuador and El
Salvador, which use the U.S. dollar, and Montenegro and Kosovo, which use the
euro but are not members of the Eurozone. Countries with fixed exchange rates
include Saudi Arabia and several other Middle Eastern oil producers, which peg
to the dollar, and several African countries, which peg to the euro. Finally,
there is the special case of Eurozone members themselves, which do not have
separate currencies but do have a vote in the policies of the ECB, which
manages the euro.
Any external shock to an economy, even a favorable one such
as an increase in the global market price of a major export, creates a cascade
of effects with both winners and losers.
Economists have long studied the question of whether two or
more countries are better off with shared or independent currencies. They agree on one point:
currency areas work best when member countries are likely to be subject to
similar economic shocks. For example, other things equal, two energy exporters
might share a currency, but sharing would make less sense for an energy importer
and an exporter. In many ways the same principle applies to the choice between
fixed or floating exchange rates for countries with independent currencies.
Any external shock to a country’s economy, even a favorable
one such as an increase in the global market price of a major export, creates a
cascade of effects with both winners and losers. An export boom can push up
input prices for producers in other sectors in the same country. A rise in
import prices harms consumers but benefits producers of home-grown substitutes
for imports. And so on.
When a country has its own currency, its central bank can
mitigate the effects of such shocks. It can apply stimulus to avoid the pain of
deflation, or control inflation by raising interest rates. A country that uses
another’s currency has no such option. The central bank of Ecuador can do
nothing to affect the exchange rate of the dollar, interest rates on U.S.
government bonds or the quantity of dollars in circulation within its own
borders.
Members of the Eurozone are a little better off, since each
of them has a voice in decisions of the European Central Bank. But the ECB
can’t — and certainly doesn’t — please everyone all the time. The Greek debt
crisis that followed the global financial meltdown of 2007-8 is a case in
point. The perceived interests of Germany and Greece diverged so sharply during
that episode that Greece came close to leaving the Eurozone altogether.
Even countries that have their own currencies can get into
trouble when they tie their exchange rates to other currencies. If the central
bank of a fixed-rate country tries to stimulate its economy by cutting interest
rates, it risks creating a run on its reserves of foreign currency. If its
treasury tries to finance government spending by borrowing abroad, it can
undermine investor confidence and risk a default on its debt.
Here, Argentina is the poster child. To stop a
hyperinflation in the early 1990s, Argentina pegged its currency firmly to the
U.S. dollar. As far as inflation went, the policy worked. But it left the
Argentine central bank unable to cope with a severe recession a decade later.
In 2000, the country abandoned its currency peg and defaulted on its debt,
leading to a severe crisis.
It is often a close call whether a country is better off
within a currency area or outside it, or whether it would best have a fixed or
floating exchange rate. An increase in the frequency and severity of relative
price shocks driven by climate change could well tip the decision, causing some
countries to consider moving away from shared currencies and fixed exchange
rates toward floating rates.
Even the Eurozone is not immune. A 2013 retrospective on
the effects of the global financial crisis concluded
flatly that the Eurozone “does not currently represent an optimum currency
area,” implying that the impact of economic shocks varied widely among members.
The bloc survived, but in view of its diversity of climates, products and
consumption patterns, it seems likely that climate change will pose an ongoing
challenge to its survival.
The bottom line
Trends since the turn of the century and projections for the
future make it clear that climate change will leave no part of the economy
untouched. Central banks, like the rest of us, will have to deal with this
reality. In particular, they will have to cope with the possibility of
persistent upward pressure on the relative prices of climate-sensitive products
such as food, as well as larger and more frequent shocks that can strike any
sector of the economy.
Fortunately, central bankers are not without options.
Inflation-targeting countries will have to rethink the 2 percent inflation goal
that most of them have adopted, sometimes without much reflection. Going
forward, 2 percent may not give enough room for stimulus in times of trouble.
By the same token, policymakers may also want to reconsider which measures of
inflation they use as benchmarks along with the time horizon they select for
bringing inflation under control.
Central banks that impose fixed exchange rates already face
constraints on inflation policy that make adjustment to shocks more difficult.
We may see fewer countries opt for fixed exchange-rate pegs going forward.
Countries in currency unions (like the Eurozone) and those that have adopted
another country’s currency unilaterally face even tighter constraints. The
Eurozone has brought considerable benefits by reducing trade barriers and
facilitating capital flows among member countries, but past shocks have already
pushed it to the limit. It is worth thinking in advance about who is better in
the euro area and who is not, rather than waiting for the next crisis to force
a choice at an inopportune moment.
Unfortunately, even the wisest policies will not entirely
shield economies from coming climate impacts. Every shock will produce both
winners and losers. The best course will be to maintain enough policy
flexibility in advance to manage climate effects in ways that spread the pain
in as balanced a way as possible.
Originally published by Milken Institute Review. Reposted with permission.
No comments:
Post a Comment