A new report from the National Academies of Science, Engineering, and Medicine (NASEM), An Updated Measure of Poverty: (Re)Drawing the Line, has hit Washington with something of a splash. Its proposals deserve a warm welcome across the political spectrum. Unfortunately, they are not always getting it from the conservative side of the aisle.
The AEI’s Kevin Corinth sees the NASEM proposals as a path to adding billions of dollars to federal spending. Congressional testimony by economist Bruce Meyer takes NASEM to task for outright partisan bias. Yet in their more analytical writing, these and other conservative critics offer many of the same criticisms of the obsolete methods that constitute the current approach to measuring poverty. As I will explain below, many of their recommendations for improvements are in harmony with the NASEM report. Examples include the need for better treatment of healthcare costs, the inclusion of in-kind benefits in resource measures, and greater use of administrative data rather than surveys.
After some reading, I have come to think that the disconnect
between the critics’ political negative reaction to the NASEM report and their accurate
analysis of flaws in current poverty measures has less to do with the
conceptual basis of the new proposals and more with the way they should be put
to work. That comes more clearly into focus if we distinguish between what we
might call the tracking and the treatment functions,
or macro and micro functions, of poverty
measurement.
The tracking function has an analytic focus. It is a matter
of assessing how many people are poor at a given time and tracing how their
number varies in response to changes in policies and economic conditions. The
treatment function, in contrast, has an administrative focus. It sets a poverty
threshold that can be used to determine who is eligible for specific government
programs and what their benefits will be.
There are parallels in the tracking and treatment methods
that were developed during the Covid-19 pandemic. By early in 2020, it was
clear to public health officials that something big was happening, but slow and
expensive testing made it hard to track how and where the SARS-CoV-2 virus was
spreading. Later, as tests became faster and more accurate, tracking improved.
Wastewater testing made it possible to track the spread of the virus to whole
communities even before cases began to show up in hospitals. As time went by,
improved testing methods also led to better treatment decisions at the micro
level. For example, faster and more accurate home antigen tests enabled
effective use of treatments like Paxlovid, which works best if taken soon after
symptoms develop.
Poverty measurement, like testing for viruses, also plays essential roles in both tracking and treatment. For maximum effectiveness, what we need is a poverty measure that can be used at both the macro and micro level. The measures now in use are highly flawed in both applications. Both the NASEM report itself and the works of its critics offer useful ideas about where we need to go. The following sections will deal first with the tracking function, then with the treatment function, and then with what needs to be done to devise a poverty measure suitable for both uses.
The tracking function of poverty measurement
As a tracking tool, the purpose of any poverty measure is to
improve understanding. Each proposed measure represents the answer to a
specific question. To understand poverty fully – what it is, how it has
changed, who is poor, and why – we need to ask lots of questions. At this macro
level, it is misguided to look for the one best measure of poverty.
First some basics. All of the poverty measures discussed
here consist of two elements, a threshold, or measure of needs, and
a measure of resources available to meet those needs. The
threshold is based on a basic bundle of goods and services
considered essential for a minimum acceptable standard of living. The first
step in deriving a threshold is to define the basic bundle and determine its
cost. The basic bundle can be defined in absolute terms or relative to median standards
of living. If absolute, the cost of the basic bundle can be adjusted from year
to year to reflect inflation, and if relative, to reflect changes in the
median. Once the cost of the basic bundle is established, poverty thresholds
themselves may be adjusted to reflect the cost of essentials not explicitly
listed in the basic bundle. Further adjustments in the thresholds may be
developed to reflect household size and regional differences.
Similarly, a poverty measure can include a narrower or
broader definition of resources. A narrow definition might consider only a
household’s regular inflows of cash. A broader definition might include the
cash-equivalent value of in-kind benefits, benefits provided through the tax
system, withdrawals from retirement savings, and other sources of purchasing
power.
Finally, a poverty measure needs to specify the economic
unit to which it applies. In some cases, that may be an individual. In other
cases, it may be a family (a group related by kinship, marriage, adoption, or
other legal ties) or a household (a group of people who live together and share
resources regardless of kinship or legal relationships). Putting it all
together, an individual, family, or household is counted as poor if their
available resources are less than the applicable poverty threshold.
The current official poverty measure (OPM), which dates from
the early 1960s, includes very simple versions of each of these components. It
defines the basic bundle in absolute terms as three times the cost of a
“thrifty food plan” determined by the U.S. Department of Agriculture. It then
converts that to a set of thresholds for family units that vary by family size,
with special adjustments for higher cost of living in Alaska and Hawaii. The
OPM defines resources as before-tax regular cash income, including wages,
salaries, interest, and retirement income; cash benefits such as Temporary
Assistance for Needy Families and Supplemental Security Income; and a few other
items. Importantly, the OPM does not include tax credits or the cash-equivalent
value of in-kind benefits in its resource measure.
The parameters of the OPM were initially calibrated to
produce a poverty rate for 1963 of approximately 20 percent. After that, annual
inflation adjustments used the CPI-U, which to this day remains the most widely
publicized price index. As nominal incomes rose due to economic growth and
inflation, and as cash benefits increased, the share of the population living
below the threshold fell. By the early 1970s, it had reached 12 percent. Since
then, however, despite some cyclical ups and downs, it has changed little.
Today, nearly everyone views the OPM as functionally
obsolete. Some see it as overstating the poverty rate, in that its measure of
resources ignores in-kind benefits like the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance
Program (SNAP) and tax credits like the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC). Others
see it as understating poverty on the grounds that three times the cost of food
is no longer enough to meet minimal needs for shelter, healthcare, childcare,
transportation, and modern communication services. Almost no one sees the OPM
as just right.
In a recent paper in the Journal of
Political Economy, Richard V. Burkhauser, Kevin Corinth, James
Elwell, and Jeff Larrimore provide an excellent overview of the overstatement
perspective. The question they ask is what percentage of American households
today lack the resources they need to reach the original three-times-food
threshold. Simply put, was Lyndon Johnson’s “War on Poverty,” on its own terms,
a success or failure?
To answer that question, they develop what they call
an absolute full-income poverty measure (FPM). Their first
step in creating the FPM was to include more expense categories in the basic
bundle, but calibrate it to make the FPM poverty rate for 1963 equal to the OPM
rate for that year. Next, they expanded the resource measure to reflect the
growth of in-kind transfer programs and the effects of taxes and tax credits.
They also adopt the household, rather than the family, as their basic unit of
analysis. Burkhauser et al. estimate that adding the full value of the EITC and
other tax credits to resources, along with all in-kind transfer programs, cuts
the poverty rate in 2019 to just 4 percent, far below the official 10.6
percent.
Going further, Burkhauser et al. raise the issue of the
appropriate measure of the price level to be used in adjusting poverty
thresholds over time. They note that many economists consider that the
CPI-U overstates
the rate of inflation, at least for the economy as a whole. Instead,
they prefer the personal consumption expenditure (PCE) index, which the Fed
uses as a guide to monetary policy. Replacing the CPI-U with the PCE reduces
the FPM poverty rate for 2019 to just 1.6 percent. It is worth noting, however,
that some observers maintain that prices in the basket of goods purchased by
poor households tend to rise at a faster rate than the average for all
households. In that case, an FPM adjusted for inflation using the PCE would not
fully satisfy one of the criteria set by Burkhauser et al., namely, that “the
poverty measure should reflect the share of people who lack a minimum level of
absolute resources.” (For further discussion of this point, see, e.g., this
report to the Office of Management and Budget.)
Burkhauser et al. do not represent 1.6 percent as the “true”
poverty rate. As they put it, although the FPM does point to “the near
elimination of poverty based on standards from more than half a century ago,”
they see that as “an important but insufficient indication of progress.” For a
fuller understanding, measuring success or failure of Johnson’s War on Poverty
is not enough. A poverty measure for today should give a better picture of the
basic needs of today’s households and the resources available to them.
The Supplemental
Poverty Measure (SPM), which the Census Bureau has published since
2011, is the best known attempt to modernize the official measure. The SPM
enlarges the OPM’s basic bundle of essential goods to include not only food,
but also shelter, utilities, telephone, and internet. It takes a relative
approach, setting the threshold as a percentage of median expenditures and
updating it not just for inflation, but also for the growth in real median
household income. On the resource side, the SPM adds many cash and in-kind benefits,
although not as many as the FPM. It further adjusts measured resources by
deducting some necessary expenses, such as childcare and out-of-pocket
healthcare costs. Finally, the SPM moves away from the family as its unit of
analysis toward a household concept.
Since the SPM adds items to both thresholds and resources,
it could, depending on its exact calibration, have a value either higher or
lower than the OPM. In practice, as shown in Figure 1, it has tracked a little
higher than the OPM. (For comparison, Burkhauser et al. calculate a variant of
their FPM that uses a relative rather than an absolute poverty threshold. The
relative FPM, not shown in Figure 1, tracks slightly higher than the SPM in
most years.)
That brings us back to our starting point, the NASEM report.
Its centerpiece is a recommended revision of the SPM that it calls the
principal poverty measure (PPM). The PPM directly addresses several
acknowledged shortcomings of the SPM. Some of the most important
recommendations include:
- A
further movement toward the household as the unit of analysis. To
accomplish that, the PPM would place more emphasis on groups of people who
live together and less on biological and legal relationships.
- A
change in the treatment of healthcare costs. The SPM treats out-of-pocket
healthcare spending as a deduction from resources but does not treat
healthcare as a basic need. The PPM adds the cost of basic health
insurance to its basic package of needs, adds the value of subsidized
insurance (e.g., Medicaid or employer-provided) to its list of resources,
and (like the SPM) deducts any remaining out-of-pocket healthcare spending
from total resources.
- A
change in the treatment of the costs of shelter that does a better job of
distinguishing between the situation faced by renters and homeowners.
- Inclusion
of childcare as a basic need and subsidies to childcare as a resource.
Although Burkhauser et al. do not directly address the PPM,
judging by their criticisms of the SPM, it seems likely that they would regard
nearly all of these changes as improvements. Many of the changes
recommended in the NASEM report make the PPM more similar to the FPM than is
the SPM.
Since the NASEM report makes recommendations regarding
methodology for the PPM but does not calculate values, the PPM is not shown in
Figure 1. In principle, because it modifies the way that both needs and
resources are handled, the PPM could, depending on its exact calibration,
produce poverty rates either above or below the SPM.
Measurement for treatment
The OPM, FPM, SPM, and PPM are just a few of the many
poverty measures that economists have proposed over the years. When we confine
our attention to tracking poverty, each of them adds to our understanding. When
we turn to treatment, however, things become more difficult. A big part of the
reason is that none of the above measures is really suitable for making
micro-level decisions regarding the eligibility of particular households for
specific programs.
For the OPM, that principle is laid out explicitly in U.S.
Office of Management and Budget Statistical Policy Directive No. 14,
first issued in 1969 and revised in 1978:
The poverty levels used by the Bureau of the Census were
developed as rough statistical measures to record changes in the number of
persons and families in poverty and their characteristics, over time. While
they have relevance to a concept of poverty, these levels were not developed
for administrative use in any specific program and nothing in this Directive
should be construed as requiring that they should be applied for such a
purpose.
Despite the directive, federal and state agencies do use the
OPM, or measures derived from it, to determine eligibility for many programs,
including Medicaid, SNAP, the Women, Infants, and Children nutrition program,
Affordable Care Act premium subsidies, Medicare Part D low-income subsidies,
Head Start, and the National School Lunch Program. The exact eligibility
thresholds and the rules for calculating resources vary from program to
program. The threshold at which eligibility ends or phase-out begins for a
given household may be equal to the Census Bureau’s official poverty threshold,
a fraction of that threshold, or a multiple of it. The resource measure may be
regular cash income as defined by the OPM, or a modification based on various
deductions and add-backs. Some programs include asset tests as well as income
tests in their measures of resources. The exact rules for computing thresholds
and resources vary not only from one program to another, but from state to
state.
That brings us to what is, perhaps, the greatest source of
alarm among conservative critics of the NASEM proposals. That is the concern
that a new poverty measure such as the PPM would be used in a way that raised
qualification thresholds while resource measures remained unchanged. It is easy
to understand how doing so by administrative action could be seen as a backdoor
way of greatly increasing welfare spending without proper legislative
scrutiny.
Kevin Corinth articulates this fear in a recent
working paper for the American Enterprise Institute. He notes that
while the resource measures that agencies should use in screening applications
are usually enshrined in statute, the poverty thresholds are not. If the Office
of Management and Budget were to put its official stamp of approval on a new
poverty measure such as the SPM or PPM, Corinth maintains that agencies would
fall in line and recalculate their thresholds based on the new measure without
making any change in the way they measure resources.
Corinth calculates that if the current OPM-based thresholds
were replaced by new thresholds derived from the SPM, federal spending for SNAP
and Medicaid alone would increase by $124 billion by 2033. No similar
calculation can be made for the PPM, since it has not been finalized, but
Corinth presumes that it, too, would greatly increase spending if it were used
to recalculate thresholds while standards for resources remained unchanged.
Clearly, Corinth is onto a real problem. The whole
conceptual basis of the SPM and PPM is to add relevant items in a balanced
manner to both sides of the poverty equation, so that they more accurately
reflect the balance between the cost of basic needs and the resources available
to meet them. Changing one side of the equation while leaving the other
untouched makes little sense.
Logically, then, what we need is an approach to poverty
measurement that is both conceptually balanced and operationally suitable for
use at both the macro and micro levels. Corinth himself acknowledges that at
one point, when he notes that “changes could be made to both the SPM resource
measure and SPM thresholds.” However, he does not follow up with specific
recommendations for doing so. To fill the gap, I offer some ideas of my own in
the next section.
Toward a balanced approach to micro-level poverty
measurement
To transform the PPM from a tracking tool into one suitable
for determining individual households’ eligibility for specific public
assistance programs would require several steps.
1. Finalize a package of basic needs. For
the PPM, those would include food, clothing, telephone, internet, housing needs
based on fair market rents, basic health insurance, and childcare. The NASEM
report recommends calibrating costs based on a percentage of median
expenditures, but conceptually, they could instead be set in absolute terms,
either based on costs in a given year or averaged over a fixed period leading
up to the date of implementation of the new approach.
2. Convert the package of needs into thresholds. Thresholds
would vary according to the size and composition of the household unit. They
could also vary geographically, although there is room for debate on how fine
the calibration should be. Thresholds would be updated to reflect changes in
the cost of living as measured by changes in median expenditures or (in the
absolute version) changes in price levels.
3. Finalize a list of resources. These
would include cash income plus noncash benefits that households can use to meet
food, clothing, and telecommunication needs; plus childcare subsidies, health
insurance benefits and subsidies, rent subsidies, and (for homeowners) imputed
rental income; minus tax payments net of refundable tax credits; minus work
expenses, nonpremium out-of-pocket medical expenses, homeowner costs if
applicable, and child support paid to another household.
4. Centralize collection of data on resources. Determining
eligibility of individual households for specific programs would require
assembling data from many sources. It would be highly beneficial to centralize
the reporting of total resources as much as possible, so that all resource data
would be available from a central PPM database. The IRS could provide data on
cash income other than public benefits (wages, salaries, interest, dividends,
etc.) and payments made to households through refundable tax credits such as
the EITC. The federal or state agencies that administer SNAP, Medicaid and
other programs could provide household-by-household data directly to the PPM
database. Employers could report the cash-equivalent value of employer-provided
health benefits along with earnings and taxable benefits.
5. Devise a uniform format for reporting eligible
deductions from resources. Individual households applying for
benefits from specific programs would be responsible for reporting applicable
deductions from resources, such as work expenses, out-of-pocket medical
expenses, homeowner costs and so on. A uniform format should be developed for
reporting those deductions along with uniform standards for documenting them so
that the information could be submitted to multiple benefit programs without
undue administrative burden.
6. Use net total resources as the basis for all
program eligibility. Decisions on eligibility for individual
programs should use net total resources, as determined by steps (4) and (5), to
determine eligibility for individual programs.
7. Harmonization of program phase-outs. It
would be possible to implement steps (1) through (6) without making major
changes to the phase-in and phaseout rules for individual programs. However,
once a household-by-household measure of net total resources became available,
it would be highly desirable to use it to compute benefit phaseouts from all
programs in a harmonized fashion. At present, for example, a household just
above the poverty line might face a phaseout rate of 24 percent for SNAP and 21
percent for EITC, giving it an effective marginal tax rate of 45 percent, not
counting other programs or income and payroll taxes. As explained in this
previous commentary, such high effective marginal tax rates impose
severe work disincentives, especially on families that are just making the
transition from poverty to self-sufficiency. Replacing the phase-outs for
individual programs with a single harmonized “tax” on total resources as
computed by the PPM formula could significantly mitigate work
disincentives.
Implementing all of these steps would clearly be a major
administrative and legislative undertaking. However, the result would be a
public assistance system that was ultimately simpler, less prone to error, and
less administratively burdensome both for government agencies at all levels and
for poor households.
Conclusion
In a recent
commentary for the Foundation for Research on Equal Opportunity,
Michael Tanner points to the potentially far-reaching significance of proposed
revisions to the way poverty is measured. “Congress should use this opportunity
to debate even bigger questions,” he writes, such as “what is poverty, and how
should policymakers measure it?” Ultimately, he continues, “attempts to develop
a statistical measure of poverty venture beyond science, reflecting value
judgments and biases. Such measures cannot explain everything about how the
poor really live, how easily they can improve their situation, or how
policymakers can best help them.”
The “beyond science” caveat is worth keeping in mind for all
discussions of poverty measurement. A case in point is the issue of whether to
use an absolute or relative approach in defining needs. It is not that one is
right and the other wrong. Rather, they reflect fundamentally different
philosophies as to what poverty is. For example, as noted earlier, Burkhauser
et al. compute both absolute and relative versions of their full-income poverty
measure. The absolute version is the right one for answering the historical
question they pose about the success or failure of the original War on Poverty,
but for purposes of policy today, the choice is not so clear. Some might see an
absolute measure, when used in a micro context, as producing too many false
negatives, that is, failures to help those truly in need. Others might see the
relative approach as producing too many false positives, spending hard-earned
taxpayer funds on people who could get by on their own if they made the effort.
The choice is more a matter of values than of science.
The choice of a price index for adjusting poverty measures
over time also involves values as well as science. Should the index be one
based on average consumption patterns for all households, such as the PCE or
chained CPI-U, or should it be a special index based on the consumption
patterns of low-income households? Should the index be descriptive, that is,
based on observed consumption patterns for the group in question? Or should it
be prescriptive, that is, based on a subjective estimate of “basics needed to
live and work in the modern economy” as is the approach taken by the ALICE Essentials
Index?
In closing, I would like to call attention to four
additional reasons why conservative critics of existing poverty policy should
welcome the proposed PPM, even in its unfinished state, as a major step in the
right direction.
The PPM is inherently less prone to error. Bruce Meyer is
concerned that “the NAS[EM]-proposed changes to poverty measurement would
produce a measure of poverty that does a worse job identifying the most
disadvantaged, calling poor those who are better off and not including others
suffering more deprivation.” In fact, many features of the PPM make it
inherently less prone than either the OPM or the SPM to both false positives
and false negatives. The most obvious is its move toward a full-income
definition of resources. That avoids one of the most glaring flaws in the OPM,
namely, the identification of families as poor who in fact receive sufficient
resources in the form of in-kind transfers or tax credits. The PPM also
addresses some of the flaws of the SPM that Meyer singles out in his testimony,
most notably in the treatment of healthcare. Furthermore, by placing
greater emphasis on administrative data sources and less on surveys, the PPM
would mitigate underreporting of income and benefits, which Burkhauser et al.
identify as a key weakness of the SPM. (See NASEM Recommendations 6.2 and 6.3).
The PPM offers a pathway toward consistency and
standardization in poverty policy. In his critique of the
PPM, Tanner suggests that “Congress should decouple program eligibility from
any single poverty measure, and adopt a broader definition of poverty that
examines the totality of the circumstances that low-income people face and their
potential to rise above them.” I see that kind of decoupling as exactly the
wrong approach. Our existing welfare system is already a clumsy accretion
of mutually inconsistent means-tested programs – as many as 80 of them, by
one count. It is massively wasteful and daunting to navigate. In large
part that is precisely because each component represents a different view of
the “totality of circumstances” of the poor as seen by different policymakers
at different times. What we need is not decoupling, but standardization and
consistency. The proposed system-wide redefinition of poverty offers a perfect
opportunity to make real progress in that direction.
The PPM would be more family-friendly. One
pro-family feature of the PPM is its recognition of childcare costs on both the
needs and the resources sides of the poverty equation. In addition, by moving
toward households (defined by resource-sharing) rather than families (defined
by legal relationships), the PPM would mitigate the marriage
penalties that are built into some of today’s OPM-based poverty
programs.
Properly implemented, the PPM would be more
work-friendly. As noted above, the benefit cliffs,
disincentive deserts, and high effective marginal tax rates of existing
OPM-based poverty programs create formidable work disincentives. Moving toward
a harmonized phaseout system based on the PPM’s full-income approach to
resources could greatly reduce work disincentives, especially for households
just above the poverty line that are struggling to take the last steps toward
self-sufficiency.
In short, it is wrong to view the proposed PPM as part of a
progressive plot to raid the government budget for the benefit of the
undeserving, as some conservative critics seem to have done. Rather, both
conservatives and progressives should embrace the PPM as a promising step
forward and direct their efforts toward making sure it is properly
implemented.
Based on a version originally published by Niskanen Center.
No comments:
Post a Comment