President-elect Joe Biden will face serious fiscal policy challenges as soon as he takes office. A hoped-for V-shaped recovery from the Covid-19 pandemic has turned into a something that looks more like a long-tailed Nike swoosh. Business closings, mostly classed as temporary back in March and April, are, increasingly, proving to be permanent. Short-term unemployment is falling, but long-term unemployment and involuntary part-time work are increasing. Evictions and foreclosures loom over cash-poor working-classfamilies, who are estimated to have accumulated as much as $70 billion in back rent owed. Meanwhile, state and local governments, whose spending is constrained by balanced-budget rules, are laying off teachers and fire fighters. The trade deficit remains high and the Fed has no room left to cut rates to stimulate investment.
In a normal world, such a situation would cry out for fiscal
stimulus. Ominously, however, the deficit hawks of the Republican party, who
slept through the badly timed and budget-busting Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017,
are starting to stir. They said “No” to any last-minute stimulus before the
2020 election, and their appetite for austerity will be ravenous once they are
fully awake. If Republicans hold their majority in Congress, they will have a
major role in determining policy in 2021, so little is going to get done
without at least a scintilla of bipartisanship.
“But,” you say … “Aren’t the budget hawks right this time? Just
look at the numbers!”
Yes, they are right to point out that under current policies, as measured by the Congressional Budget Office, the federal debt is rising fast. It is about to exceed its previous record as a percentage of GDP and it is projected to go on rising for the next 30 years. But those raw numbers tell us little of use for fiscal policy. A rational set of budget rules neither automatically precludes nor condones large budget deficits or a debt ratio that rises over time. To understand what a rational set of budget rules would actually look like, read on.
Procedural rules are not enough
Congress does have rules to guide fiscal policy. The 1974 Budget
Act specified a set of procedural rules that Congress is supposed to follow
each year in passing a budget. However, Congress has passed the full set of
appropriations bills on schedule only three times in the past 40 years.
Even more problematic is the failure to align annual tax and
spending decisions, whether made on time or not, with long-run goals of
stability and economic growth. Attempts to address that problem have proved
inadequate.
Consider the debt ceiling, first enacted more than 100 years ago.
Even if we could accurately determine the point beyond which debt becomes
excessive (we cannot), the ceiling in its current form is unworkable. Since it
is set in nominal terms, with no allowance for inflation or growth of the
economy, Congress must vote periodically to raise it. That creates
opportunities for various factions to disrupt the budgeting process with
brinkmanship over extraneous issues, even though everyone knows that the
consequence of not raising the ceiling — default on the debt — would be so dire
as to make the whole process a charade.
A more recent type of rule, known as pay-as-you-go, or PAYGO, has
fared little better. PAYGO has taken several forms since it was first
established in 1990, but the underlying idea is to require that tax cuts or new
spending be offset by tax increases or spending cuts elsewhere in the budget.
In case the necessary offsets are not made, sequestration — mandatory cuts to
already authorized programs — can be invoked to prevent an increase in the
deficit. In practice, however, Congress can, and does, waive PAYGO rules
whenever it wants to. For example, it used a waiver to allow the 2017 tax cut
to go into effect despite the resulting increase in the deficit.
Long-term rules for fiscal policy
If procedural rules are not enough, what would work better? The
answer is that if we want a more responsible fiscal policy, we will need to
rely less on the short-term impulses of politicians and more on policy rules
that target stable, sustainable growth. Here are three suggestions.
Rule 1: First, do no harm.
The economic equivalent of this classic medical maxim is to aim
for cyclical neutrality, that is, one that that manages taxes and spending in a
way that avoids prolonging expansions or deepening recessions.
At first glance, it might seem that the ideal neutral policy would
be to keep the budget in balance at all times. A balanced budget amendment
aimed at doing just that Is a perennial favorite of congressional
conservatives. In reality, though, nothing could be worse. As I explained in an
earlier commentary, a balanced budget amendment would be profoundly
procyclical. To keep the budget in absolute balance year-in and year-out would
require tax increases or spending cuts during downturns and spending increases
or tax cuts when the economy was at or above full employment. That would be the
exact opposite of “do no harm.”
In contrast, a cyclically neutral rule would take full advantage
of so-called automatic stabilizers to moderate the business cycle. Automatic
stabilizers are elements of the budget that provide fiscal stimulus during a
recession or restraint during an expansion. Examples include the tendency of
unemployment benefits to increase and income tax receipts to decrease during a
recession.
One form of such a rule would be to hold the primary structural
balance of the budget at a constant target value over time. The primary
structural balance differs from the ordinary way of measuring the federal
deficit or surplus in two ways:
- The “structural” part means that the actual surplus in any year is adjusted to reflect the levels of tax receipts and spending that would prevail, under current law, if the economy were at full employment. During a recession, the actual balance is below the structural balance (that is, further toward deficit) because automatic stabilizers reduce tax revenue and increase spending on income transfers. When the economy is running hot, the actual balance is above the structural balance (that is, further toward surplus).
- The “primary” part of the term means that interest payments on the national debt are disregarded. Although interest payments are a form of government outlay, in the short run, they are not under the control of policymakers. Instead, for any given level of debt, federal interest expenditures are largely determined by market interest rates.
The target for the primary structural balance could be set at
zero, at a small surplus, or at a moderate deficit. The choice depends in part
on variables like the economy’s long-run rate of growth relative to market
interest rates, and also on whether policymakers want to hold total debt steady
as a share of GDP, to allow it to grow gradually, or to decrease it. I have lay
out the details of the math behind the choice of targets in a chapter for the
book A Fiscal Cliff published recently by the Cato Institute. (For another
version, see this slideshow).
To skip over the equations, at present, and for the foreseeable
future, long-term real interest rates in the United States are well below
long-term growth of real GDP. Under those conditions, a budget surplus is not
necessary to reduce the debt ratio in the long run. A zero primary structural
balance, or even a small deficit of, say, half a percent of GDP, would be
sufficient to achieve cyclical neutrality while ensuring that the current rapid
growth of the debt ratio would slow over time and, eventually, decrease.
Rule 1a: Emergency exceptions
In the second quarter of 2020, the economic shock of the Covid-19
pandemic drove the unemployment rate to nearly 15 percent and cut 9 percent
from real GDP. Under those conditions, automatic stabilizers alone would have
caused a sharp increase in the federal deficit. However, the stimulus produced
by automatic stabilizers alone would not have been enough to ensure a quick
recovery.
The fact is that when the economy encounters a shock so much
larger than that of the typical business cycle, we need a degree of fiscal
stimulus greater than what primary structural balance rule would permit. At the
same time, however, it we need some safeguard that would prevent waiving the
rule for purely political reasons. How could that be done?
One possible emergency exception would be to allow extra fiscal
stimulus during periods when interest rates fall to the zero bound, rendering
conventional monetary stimulus ineffective. This time around, the Fed cut its
benchmark interest rate to zero on March 16, very early in the pandemic. Under
the suggested emergency exception, that would have provided room for the CARES
Act and other stimulus measures used to counter the effects of the Covid-19
recession. At the same time, the rule would not have permitted the excessive
stimulus of the 2017 tax cuts, undertaken at a time when the economy was
nearing a cyclical peak and interest rates were well within positive territory.
Rule 2: Microeconomic aspects of fiscal policy should be
consistent with macro targets
Fiscal policy has both a macroeconomic and a microeconomic side.
Rule 1, which calls for cyclical neutrality, serves the macroeconomic goals of
stability and growth. Microeconomic issues concerning the structure of taxes
and the composition of spending are also important, but they, too, should be
approached in a manner that does no macroeconomic harm.
In particular, tax reform, whether aimed at removing perverse
incentives or improving distributional equity, should be carried out in a way
that is revenue-neutral over the business cycle. Once again, the Tax Cuts and
Jobs Act of 2017 provides a pertinant example. Whether viewed from a
conservative or a progressive perspective, a good case can be made on
microeconomic grounds for reducing the U.S. corporate tax rate, which was then
then highest in the world. However, the economy did not need additional fiscal
stimulus at a time when unemployment was low and growth was strong. Instead,
cuts to admittedly distortionary corporate-profits taxes should have been
offset by increasing other less distortionary taxes, such as the capital gainstax, or even by introducing a value added tax or carbon tax.
Like its distant cousin PAYGO, Rule 2 would require Congress to
consider impacts on the deficit when passing tax or spending legislation.
However, it differs from PAYGO in two important ways. First, it would be
symmetrical, in that it would not only bar inappropriate fiscal stimulus when
the economy is near full employment, but also premature austerity of the kind
that was implemented half-way through the recovery from the Great Recession.
Second, the degree of offset for tax cuts and spending increases would vary
with the business cycle. The required offset would be less than 100 percent
near the bottom of the cycle and greater than 100 percent at or near the peak.
Rule 3: Fiscal rules should be neutral with respect to the size of
government.
Conservatives often propose that any fiscal rule should place a
constraint on the overall size of government. For example, a 2011 version of a
balanced budget amendment proposed capping federal expenditures at 18 percent
of GDP. Such a constraint would be a mistake. Instead, any rule governing the
path of the deficit or surplus over the business cycle should be neutral as to
the size of government as well as neutral with regard to the cycle itself.
In reality, there is little evidence to support the idea that
small government is necessarily good government. On the contrary, the availableevidence shows that broad measures of freedom and prosperity all tend to be
higher in countries where governments are larger, not smaller, relative to GDP.
Overall, quality of government, as measured by such things as the rule of law,
protection of property rights, and government integrity, is more important for
freedom and prosperity than the size of government.
What is more, even if one believes, contrary to the evidence, that
a smaller government is better, building that objective into a fiscal policy
rule would inject a contentious ideological motive into the debate over how
best to manage deficits and debts. A rule that is neutral to government size
leaves the question of the size of government open to democratic debate, with
the proviso that new structural spending must be paid for.
The bottom line
The Covid-19 pandemic has revealed a need to rethink many aspects
of economic policy. The case for reform is especially strong in the case of
budget rules. The purely procedural rules that we have now, such as the debt
ceiling and PAYGO, are so full of loopholes as to make them meaningless. Overly
rigid alternatives, such as a proposed balanced budget amendment, would do more
harm than good, especially when the economy is hit by a shock as large as that
encountered in 2020. Yet between rules that are too rigid and rules that are so
weak as to be ineffective, there is a golden mean.
Those who are in charge of fiscal policy could learn a lot about
the proper balance between rules and discretion by heeding the example of the
Fed. For years, there have been economists who have urged the Fed to follow a
more rules-based policy and others who resisted those urgings. FredericMishkin, a former member of the Fed’s Board of Governors, has argued that rules
vs. discretion is not an either-or choice. Instead, Mishkin sees the Fed as
moving toward a regime of “constrained discretion” — one that pays attention to
rules but permits departures from the rules in response to unexpected economic
shocks. He argues that as long as such a regime is backed by transparent
communication of policy goals and actions, it can avoid the disadvantages both
of pure discretion and of overly rigid rules. In fact, constrained discretion
is already the Fed’s all-but-official policy.
Within the context of a primary structural budget rule, there are
other things we could do to enhance the ability of our economy to withstand
major shocks. In particular, a lot could be done to strengthen existing
automatic stabilizers. For example, it would be a good idea to extend
unemployment benefits to gig workers. The CARES Act tried to do that, but the
effort was not fully successful. A permanent version of payroll protection,
perhaps modeled on the German Kurtzarbeit system, would also be helpful. Finally,
a healthcare system that did not link insurance coverage to employment would
remove yet another source of financial stress to people thrown out of work in a
recession.
Now is the right time to start thinking about a better way to
handle the next crisis.
Based on a previous post at NiskanenCenter.org. Photo courtesy of
Pixabay.com.
No comments:
Post a Comment