A tracking poll from the Kaiser
Family Foundation finds that 56 percent of Americans favor a fully government-run
Medicare for All insurance plan, but that an even larger 68 percent favor a
mixed public-private approach with a public option. The most common reason
given by those who support a public option but oppose Medicare for All is a
desire for choice. They do not oppose the idea of public health insurance, but
they do not want to be forced onto it.
Given those public attitudes, it is not surprising that many
Democratic presidential aspirants have shied away from Medicare for All in
favor of plans based on a public option. Pete Buttigieg emphasizes the element
of choice in the very name of his plan, which he calls Medicare
for All Who Want It. Other candidates backing
one or another form of public option include Joe Biden, Amy Klobuchar, and
Michael Bloomberg.
There is a dilemma at the heart of the public option
approach, however. Is it possible to offer choice in health care coverage and
still achieve universal coverage, another cherished goal of reformers? Or does
the attempt to achieve universality inevitably require making enrollment
compulsory?
In my view, it should be possible to preserve meaningful choice in health care while ensuring universal access to coverage. But doing so will require attention to some details of program design that the candidates’ plans have not fully addressed.
The issue
Although the universal-vs.-voluntary dilemma is inherent in
all public option plans, the version advanced by the Buttigieg campaign has
drawn the most attention to the issue. At least part of the reason is that the
Buttigieg plan comes closest to addressing the dilemma directly. Writers for The
Washington Post, The
New Republic, the Wall
Street Journal, and Slate
have all argued that his public option is designed in such a way that it would
inevitably become compulsory.
The central question in all of this is how to ensure that
the risk pool covered by the public option includes an adequate number of healthy
subscribers along with those who are ill. If people can easily buy into
coverage only after they become sick and drop out at will when they recover,
the average cost of claims made by those left in the pool rises and premiums
become unaffordable. The result is the notorious “death spiral,” known to
economists as adverse selection.
One way to control adverse selection would be to make
coverage mandatory. The Affordable Care Act included a step in that direction
in the form of a tax penalty for healthy people who did not obtain coverage. Unfortunately,
that “individual mandate” proved to be one of the least politically popular
aspects of the ACA. Shaken by court
challenges and rendered
meaningless by Congress, the individual mandate is no longer in force.
Another way to deal with adverse selection would be to
refuse care to people who do not have insurance. However, no one wants to see
people dying on the streets because doctors and hospitals have turned them away.
Already, the law
requires that anyone who makes it to an emergency room must be at least stabilized
regardless of ability to pay.
Still another approach would be to impose a late enrollment penalty for people who do not sign up for coverage when first eligible, waiting to apply for coverage only after they get sick. That is the strategy used by Medicare Part D prescription drug coverage. Medicare calculates the penalty by multiplying 1 percent of the "national base beneficiary premium" ($32.74 a month in 2020) times the number of full, uncovered months a person did not have Part D or creditable coverage. For example, suppose someone was not enrolled for 30 months before finally enrolling in February 2020. The monthly premium penalty would be 30 X 0.01 X $32.74, which comes to $9.80 a month (Medicare rounds the penalty to the nearest ten cents) or $117.60 per year, paid for the rest of the person’s life. As of 2020, the theoretical maximum annual penalty can be over $600 a year.
These approaches could be combined in any number of ways.
For example, although it does not fully spell out the details, the Buttigieg plan
appears to call for a combination of mandatory enrollment and late enrollment
penalties. In this case, however, the late enrollment penalty takes the form of
retroactive monthly premium payments for a full year of coverage rather than an
increase in premiums going forward, as under Medicare Part D. Since premiums under
the Buttigieg plan could be as high as 8.5 percent of income, retroactive
enrollment could mean an unexpected bill of thousands of dollars. The Buttigieg
team has also considered requiring people to show proof of insurance when
paying taxes. Those who could not do so would be automatically enrolled in the
public option, with premiums collected through the IRS.
Critics say that such measures would make the program
“Medicare Whether You Want It Or Not,” producing a political backlash far
greater than the Obamacare individual mandate. Fortunately, however, there are
better ways to deal with the universal-vs.-voluntary dilemma.
Guidelines for a balanced solution
1. Automatic enrollment for the poor. All
candidates’ versions of a public option include premium subsidies for people
with low incomes and waive premiums altogether for people below a low-income
cutoff, most likely set at the federal poverty level. Automatic enrollment
would be a reasonable way to achieve universal coverage for people whose
incomes were low enough to qualify for a zero premium.
For example, Biden’s version of the public option envisages automatic
enrollment for anyone below the low-income cutoff at whatever point they come
in contact with government services, such as enrolling children in school,
applying for food stamps, or renewing a driver’s license. Anyone who fell
through the cracks would be enrolled automatically the first time they sought
health care services. Since low-income people are not subject to premiums, they
would face no surprise bills or retroactive penalties.
2. Eligible income, not total income. Once
people are enrolled, administrators would have to monitor tax returns for
increases in income. It would be desirable to avoid sharp premium increases for
people who move from just below the poverty line to just above it. Such
variations in income are not unusual for low-skill workers who have sporadic
connections to the job market or who have little control over hours worked. One
way to avoid undue premium shocks would be to peg premium subsidies to “eligible
income,” rather than total income. Eligible income, in this context, means
total income minus the low-income cutoff below which premiums are fully
subsidized.
For example, suppose the low-income cutoff is equal to the federal poverty rate (about $25,000 for a family of four) and the maximum premium is set at 8.5 percent of eligible income. If the premium were based on total income, a family earning exactly $25,000 would owe no premium, but one with income of $25,100 would face a nontrivial premium of $2,133 a year, or $178 a month. Abrupt “benefit cliffs” like these distort work incentives and encourage concealment of income. If premiums were instead based on eligible income, the extra $100 of income above the low-income cutoff would mean just $8.50 a year in premium payments. Avoiding abrupt premium increases at the poverty threshold would encourage people to earn more and could reduce total spending for the insurance scheme in the long run.
3. Self-insurance as a legitimate option. Although
automatic enrollment in the public option would be appropriate for people at or
below the poverty level, I do not see it as either necessary or desirable for
those with higher incomes. Self-insurance should be a legitimate option for
people who voluntarily choose to go without insurance, provided they are
willing and able to pay their own medical expenses. Devices such as tax-free
health savings accounts make that a reasonable choice for many young, healthy
people with good incomes. Proactively hounding them to enroll is only going to
make a lot of voters angry, as did the ACA’s individual mandate.
In one sense, legitimizing self-insurance would appear to
mean giving up on the goal of universal coverage. However, universality in the
sense of universal access to insurance coverage would be maintained so
long as late enrollment in the public option (with appropriate penalties)
remained possible. Guidelines 4 and 5 explain how that could be done without
opening the door to uncontrolled adverse selection.
4. The role of a backstop fund. An
innovative provision of the Buttigieg health care plan is the use of a
“backstop fund” as a way of dealing with people who neither voluntarily sign up
for insurance nor meet the income cutoff for fully subsidized premiums.
However, the role of the backstop fund should be somewhat different than envisioned
by the Buttigieg campaign.
In the Buttigieg version, the backstop fund appears to cover the expenses of uninsured persons who seek care, and is then replenished by late-enrollment penalties (retroactive premiums) paid by those same people. In my view, the principal role of the backstop fund should instead be to protect providers, especially emergency rooms, against uncollectible bills. Under current law, hospitals end up recouping uncollected emergency room bills through higher charges on other patients, including those whose own insurance is fully in order. With a proper backstop fund, that would be unnecessary.
The backstop fund should not, however, protect the voluntarily uninsured people with adequate incomes from the need to pay for services. If such people seek non-urgent services and cannot present an insurance card, the provider should have the right to ask for payment up front. If they go to an emergency room and are not able to pay on the spot, the backstop fund should reimburse the provider but should then have the right to enroll the patient in the public option, with a substantial late-enrollment fee, possibly in the form of retroactive premiums. If the late enrollment fee is less than the charges for care, the backstop fund should have the right to seek payment of the excess amount from the patient.
5. Late enrollment. A somewhat different
problem would be posed by people who opt for self-insurance but apply for
coverage before they actually seek services. Those would include both healthy
people who simply change their mind about insurance and people who learn that
they have developed conditions such as, say, diabetes, that will require
ongoing care.
Private insurers, including employer-sponsored plans, should
be allowed to refuse such applicants or to impose actuarially fair premiums
based on preexisting conditions. The public option should be required to enroll
them at standard rates, but should apply substantial late-enrollment penalties,
perhaps modeled on that used for Medicare Part D or perhaps in the form of
retroactive premiums. (However, brief gaps in coverage should not be penalized.
For example, people who lose employer-sponsored insurance or who lose coverage
due to a change in family status should be allowed to enroll in the public
option without penalty, provided they do so promptly. For example, Medicare
Part D allows a 63-day grace period.)
Conclusions
It is understandable that many voters prefer the idea of choice that is offered by a public option over the one-size-fits-all approach of Medicare for All. However, as this commentary explains, a plan based on a public option needs to be designed carefully if it is not to fall victim to adverse selection.
A public “option” that turned out to be compulsory would be a political non-starter. A public option that had no mechanism for controlling adverse selection would not be financially viable. And a public option that provided no backup enrollment mechanism for people who initially opt for self-insurance but later face changed circumstances would not meet ethical norms of fairness. The guidelines offered above should make it possible to steer a path between these unacceptable outcomes and arrive at a program that is both universal and voluntary.
Finally, the fact that it would be possible to design a public option in a way that resolves the universal-vs.-voluntary dilemma does not mean that is the best way to go. As I have written elsewhere, a health care system based on the principle of universal catastrophic coverage could resolve the dilemma in a much more straightforward fashion. Under such a plan, everyone could automatically receive coverage for financially catastrophic health care needs without the payment of any premium. “Financially catastrophic” would be defined in relation to income, with full first-dollar coverage for the poor and full financial responsibility for the affluent. Alternatively, the Fair Care Act offers a Republican approach to health care reform that would at least come close to universal protection without public options or mandates of any kind.
Whatever approach is taken to health care reform, it is critical that the universal-vs.-voluntary dilemma not simply be ignored. Any workable plan must be designed to deal with it from the outset, or face a public backlash after the window for a suitable legislative fix has closed.
Previously posted at NiskanenCenter.com. Photo courtesy of Pixabay.com.
Ed, thanks for this interesting analysis. Universal vs voluntary dilemma is indeed further complicated by the political underpinnings.
ReplyDeleteFantastic blog. worth sharing. also i would like to suggest some websites for your promotion
ReplyDeletefree classified ads
free classified website India
free classified ads India
free classified ads USA
Post free ads
free business directory
Top business directory
Best business directory
free business directory India
free business directory usa
Top Yellowpages USA
Best yellowpages India
News website
Interesting News
weird news
Interesting facts
amazing facts
medical billing company in florida
medical billing company in USA
Strange "water hack" burns 2 lbs in your sleep
ReplyDeleteMore than 160000 men and women are utilizing a easy and SECRET "liquid hack" to lose 2lbs each night while they sleep.
It is easy and it works on anybody.
You can do it yourself by following these easy steps:
1) Take a drinking glass and fill it up half the way
2) And now use this crazy hack
and you'll be 2lbs thinner when you wake up!