The idea of a universal basic income (UBI) has been getting a lot of
attention recently, sparked in part by the Swiss decision to hold a
referendum on the idea. A UBI differs from other income support policies
in that it provides a cash grant, large enough to meet basic needs of
living, to every member of society, regardless of other sources of
income.
The first post
in this series compared a UBI to other income support policies in terms
of effectiveness in reducing poverty, work incentives, targeting, and
administrative efficiency. The second post
argued that a UBI with a per person grant approaching current official
poverty thresholds would be affordable without increasing the federal
budget deficit, raising marginal tax rates, or radically raiding the
fortunes of the rich. This third post looks at the varying perspectives
of conservatives, progressives, and libertarians, explaining why there
are both supporters and opponents of a UBI in each camp.>>>Read more
Thursday, January 30, 2014
Thursday, January 16, 2014
How Alarmed Should We Be About the Rise in Part-Time Work?
The share of part-time workers in the U.S. labor force rose to
unusually high levels during the recession of 2007-2009 and has fallen
only slowly during the subsequent recovery. As the following chart
shows, the share of workers putting in less than 35 hours a week hit a
low of 15.5 percent of the labor force in October 2007 and then rose
sharply to a peak of 18.1 percent in May 2009. As of December 2013, the
share of part time work was still over 17 percent, less than halfway
back to the pre-recession low.
Many observers find the trend toward part-time work alarming. In her blog for The New York Times, Catherine Rampell writes,
Many observers find the trend toward part-time work alarming. In her blog for The New York Times, Catherine Rampell writes,
One of the more unsettling trends in this recovery has been the rise of part-time work. We are nowhere near recovering the jobs lost in the recession, and the track record looks even worse when you consider that so many of the jobs lost were full time, whereas so many of those gained have been part time.Elsewhere, a writer for the Minnesota Budget Project laments,
Many workers are struggling to climb out of the Great Recession. They are still looking for jobs, working part time, earning less than they did before the recession, or accepting jobs that don’t meet their abilities.How worried should we be? To understand what is going on, we need to dig beneath the summary statistics shown in the chart and look the details, some of which I find surprising. >>>Read more
Monday, January 13, 2014
Could We Afford a Universal Basic Income? (Part II of Series)
The first post in this series
looked at the economic case for a universal basic income (UBI), by
which I mean an unconditional grant, paid to every individual, that
would be sufficient to maintain a decent minimum standard of living. In
that post, I argued that replacing the many overlapping income support
policies currently used in the United States with a UBI would be more
effective in raising the incomes of poor and near-poor households while
strengthening work incentives and improving administrative efficiency.
The evident economic downside is that a UBI would be less narrowly targeted on the poor than existing programs. Because it would not, by its nature, be means tested, it would channel billions of dollars in grants to middle- and upper-income households. Some think that would make a UBI unaffordable without ruinous tax increases, deficits, or cuts to other government programs. This post looks at some of the fiscal realities of a UBI and concludes that such a program might not be fiscally unrealistic after all. >>>Read more
The evident economic downside is that a UBI would be less narrowly targeted on the poor than existing programs. Because it would not, by its nature, be means tested, it would channel billions of dollars in grants to middle- and upper-income households. Some think that would make a UBI unaffordable without ruinous tax increases, deficits, or cuts to other government programs. This post looks at some of the fiscal realities of a UBI and concludes that such a program might not be fiscally unrealistic after all. >>>Read more
Saturday, January 11, 2014
US Unemployment Rate Falls to Five-Year Low of 6.7% in December but Job Growth Lags
The Bureau of Labor Statistics reported today that the U.S.
unemployment rate fell to 6.7 percent in December. As the following
chart shows, unemployment has not been that low since October 2008, more
than five years ago. According to the household survey, on which the
unemployment rate is based, the number of unemployed workers decreased
by 490,000 in the month. The labor force decreased by 347,000 workers,
leaving a net increase of 143,000 employed workers.
The BLS also tracks the number of nonfarm payroll jobs, based on a separate survey of employers. Payroll job gains for December, at 74,000, were the weakest for the year. Goods-producing industries lost 3,000 jobs, mostly because of a decline in construction activity. Manufacturing gained 9,000 jobs. Private service sector jobs rose by 90,000. Government jobs decreased by 13,000 for the month. The weak job numbers for December were partly offset by an upward revision of 38,000 to job growth previously reported for November. >>>Read more
Follow this link to view or download a classroom-ready slideshow with charts and analysis of the latest employment report
The BLS also tracks the number of nonfarm payroll jobs, based on a separate survey of employers. Payroll job gains for December, at 74,000, were the weakest for the year. Goods-producing industries lost 3,000 jobs, mostly because of a decline in construction activity. Manufacturing gained 9,000 jobs. Private service sector jobs rose by 90,000. Government jobs decreased by 13,000 for the month. The weak job numbers for December were partly offset by an upward revision of 38,000 to job growth previously reported for November. >>>Read more
Follow this link to view or download a classroom-ready slideshow with charts and analysis of the latest employment report
Friday, January 3, 2014
The Economic Case for a Universal Basic Income
The news that Switzerland
will hold a referendum on a proposal to provide every citizen with an
unconditional grant of 2,500 Swiss francs a month (about $2,800) has
sparked renewed interest in the old idea of a universal basic income (UBI).
Under such a program, the government would not just top up the incomes
of the poor, but would give a subsistence-level grant to everyone,
regardless of wealth, work status, or anything else. The appeal of a UBI
seems to cut across the ideological spectrum. Progressives,
libertarians, and conservatives have all supported one or another
variant.
This post begins a series that will explore various aspects of a universal basic income, beginning with the simple economics of the UBI and contrasting it with other approaches to income support. Future posts will examine the fiscal cost of a UBI and some of the political and ideological issues it raises.
Criteria for evaluating income support systems
What makes an income support program good or bad? Although opinions differ, people who evaluate existing or proposed policies often appeal to these four criteria:
>>>Read more
This post begins a series that will explore various aspects of a universal basic income, beginning with the simple economics of the UBI and contrasting it with other approaches to income support. Future posts will examine the fiscal cost of a UBI and some of the political and ideological issues it raises.
Criteria for evaluating income support systems
What makes an income support program good or bad? Although opinions differ, people who evaluate existing or proposed policies often appeal to these four criteria:
- A good income support program should be effective in leaving no one below an agreed poverty level.
- It should be targeted in the sense that it should provide support to those who need it rather than to those who already have adequate means.
- It would, as much is possible, leave work incentives intact.
- It would be administratively efficient, in the sense of holding down administrative costs per dollar of support that beneficiaries receive.
>>>Read more
Thursday, January 2, 2014
Austerity and the Euro in Two Graphs: A Reply to Paul Krugman
Paul Krugman started the New Year yesterday with a zingy little post in his New York Times blog titled “The State of the Euro in One Graph”. Here is the graph . . .
. . . and here is the text that accompanies it:
. . . and here is the text that accompanies it:
What you see here is that borrowing costs for the troubled euro countries have dropped a lot. But it’s not because austerity policies have brought their debt under control — debt ratios are still rising, in large part because of shrinking economies and deflation. Instead, there has been a dramatic flattening of the relationship between debt and interest rates.Oops. I see two problems here.
- If “shrinking economies” are distorting fiscal policy indicators that are stated in relation to current GDP (and they are), shouldn’t his graph measure the debt ratio relative to potential GDP, not current GDP?
- Since when is the debt ratio the proper measure of austerity policy? Austerity, which we used to call fiscal consolidation, means reduction of the deficit, not the debt. The debt ratio is too strongly influenced not only by the state of the economy, but by past fiscal history, to be a good measure of year-to-year changes in the policy stance. The chart is further muddled because debt dynamics are strongly influence by interest rates, the variable on the vertical axis.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)