In a recent post, I questioned Henry David Thoreau’s aphorism,
“That government is best which governs least.” The data, it seems, show
something different. Countries with small governments, as measured by the share
of expenditures and taxes in GDP, tend actually to be somewhat less free and
prosperous than those with larger governments. The quality of government, as
measured by things like rule of law, independent judges, and integrity of
government officials turns out to matter much more than the size of government.
I concluded that Thoreau’s aphorism should be revised to read, “That government
is best which governs well.”
In response, several readers questioned whether the size of
government, as measured by spending, was the right measure of “governs least.”
Excessive regulation, they pointed out, may do more damage than spending and
taxes. Maybe what we should say is, “That government is best which regulates least.”
Niskanen Center’s Will Wilkinson puts it this way:
Whether a country’s market economy is free — open, competitive, and relatively unmolested by government — is more a question of regulation than a question of taxation and redistribution. . .
If we want to encourage freedom and prosperity, we should pay more attention to easing the grip of the regulatory state.
The point is a good one — worth putting to the same kind of
statistical test used in the previous post. Here we go:
Data sources for prosperity: The Legatum Prosperity Index,
a composite measure of but good health; access to food, clean water, shelter
and education; safe communities; clean environment; and related indicators.
The Social
Progress Index, a similarly broad measure of human flourishing.
Data sources for freedom: The Human Freedom Index from the Cato Institute and the
Personal Freedom Index from the same source, a subset of indicators that leaves
out purely economic aspects of freedom like freedom of trade and sound money.
Data sources for regulation: The measure of
regulatory freedom from the Cato data base, and the similar regulatory
component of the Index of Economic Freedom from the Heritage Foundation. Both indicators are scaled in a way
that assigns higher scores to countries with more “regulatory freedom,” that
is, less regulation.
A first look at the data does show a positive association
between regulatory freedom and prosperity. For example, data from 131 countries
for the Heritage index of regulation and the Social Progress Index indicate
that countries with higher regulation scores (less regulation) are in fact more
prosperous. As measured by the statistic R², about 46 percent of differences in
prosperity are statistically associated with differences in regulation. Similar
findings are obtained by substituting the Cato measure of regulation or the
Legatum measure of prosperity.
However, statistical association is not the same as
causation. After all, we would find a similar positive relationship between the
heights of all children in a grade school and their scores on a standardized
math test. It would be wrong, though, to conclude that being tall makes people
better at math. The apparent relationship would be a statistical illusion
caused by the fact that sixth-graders are better at math than first-graders,
and also happen to be taller. If we corrected for age, the correlation between
height and math scores would disappear.
Much the same is true for the relationship between
regulation and social prosperity. It turns out that most of the apparent
statistical association between the two variables is a result of their level of
development, as measured by per capita GDP. At any given level of development,
whether high or low, countries with high scores for regulatory freedom do not
score much better on noneconomic aspects of prosperity (population health,
education, environmental quality, access to information, and so on) than do
countries at similar levels of development but with low regulation scores.
Similarly, once we control for differences in GDP per capita, regulation scores
have little explanatory power for between-country differences in personal
freedom.
However, it would be wrong to interpret these findings as
proof that regulation does not matter. I could be, instead, that the Cato and
Heritage indicators are just bad measures of those aspects of regulation that
are important to prosperity and freedom.
A further comment by Wilkinson gives a clue as to why this
might be the case:
Free markets require the presence of good regulations, which define and protect property rights and facilitate market processes through the consistent application of clear law, and an absence of bad regulation, which interferes with productive economic activity. A government can tax and spend very little — yet still stomp all over markets.
Wilkinson is exactly right. Bad regulation is a drag on
freedom and prosperity but good regulation facilitates them. The problem with
the Cato and Heritage indexes of regulation is that they indiscriminately
jumble together regulations of all kinds, the good with the bad. The result is
statistical mush that is incapable of explaining anything.
To distinguish the good from the bad, we need to look both
at the aims of a regulation and the way it is implemented. Good regulations are
those that have benign aims and are efficiently implemented. Bad regulations
are those that have bad intentions, or good intentions that are badly
implemented, or both.
Here are some guidelines, that can help distinguish good regulations from
bad ones:
Retain regulations that support the basic
rules of a market economy. Those include regulations that protect property
rights, ensure that contracts are honored, and protect against common law harms
like fraud, negligence, and nuisance. In principle, such rules can be enforced
through civil litigation, but courts can be slow and costly. It may, for
example, make more sense to send inspectors to ensure that nightclubs keep
their fire exits unlocked than to wait for relatives of the deceased to sue a
club’s owners for negligence after a fire occurs.
Replace regulations that have legitimate
aims but are ineffective or have harmful unintended consequences. For example,
in an effort to reduce CO2 emissions, CAFE standards set minimum gas mileage for new cars.
Meeting the standards raises the price of cars, but better fuel economy lowers
the cost per mile of driving. The unintended consequence is that people drive
more, roads are more congested, and more accidents occur. A carbon tax would be
a more efficient way to reduce emissions, since it would encourage people both
to buy efficient cars and to drive them less.
Repeal regulations that are motivated
primarily by the manipulation of public policy for private gain — what
economists call rent seeking. Regulations that restrict competition
or impose price controls rarely serve any purpose other than enriching special
interests at the expense of the public. Restrictive occupational licensing provides many
examples.
Following these “Three R’s” would do more to promote
prosperity and freedom than mindlessly cutting regulations across the board. It
is not really true that that government is best which regulates least. Rather,
that government is best which regulates well.
Previously posted on Medium. For further information on methodology and data sources
behind the statistical results, see “The
Way Economic Freedom Indexes Measure Regulation is Deeply Flawed.”
No comments:
Post a Comment