Libertarians are fond of quoting Henry David Thoreau’s
aphorism, “That government is best which governs least.” Thoreau was evidently
paraphrasing his contemporary John
O’Sullivan, but no matter who first said it, the quotation has
become an axiom of those who love freedom. But is it true?
Let’s treat this aphorism as a hypothesis and test it
against the data. To know what data we want, we first need to decide just what
we mean by “best government” and “least government.”
“Best government” could mean one of three things:
- It could mean the government that produces the best results in terms of human prosperity – not just high GDP, but good health; access to food, clean water, shelter and education; safe communities; clean environment; and so on. To measure those things, we will use the Legatum Prosperity Index (LPI).
- “Best government” could instead mean the government that allows the greatest degree of human freedom, including freedom of speech and religion, freedom in personal relationships, personal safety and security, security of property rights, freedom to trade, and so on. To measure those things, we will use the Human Freedom Index (HFI) from the Cato Institute.
- Rather than a results-based measure, we could define “best government” in a procedural sense – a government that adheres to rule of law, maintains fair and impartial criminal justice, and is free from corruption. We can compile such a measure by extracting and combining relevant indicators from the LPI and HFI to construct a Quality of Government Index (QGOV).
- Cato’s HFI includes a “size of government” component – a composite indicator that includes measures of government spending, taxes, and government enterprise. It is measured on a scale of 0 to 10, with 10 indicating the smallest government. We will abbreviate this measure as SoG.
- The SoG component of the HFI is subject to a number of methodological criticisms, so as a check, we can use a simpler measure, the ratio of government expenditures to GDP, taken from the IMF World Economic Outlook database. For easier comparison with SoG, we will convert this ratio, too, to a scale of 0 to 10, with 10 indicating the smallest government. We will abbreviate this measure of size of government as SGOV.
Now we are ready to test several versions of the hypothesis,
“That government is best which governs least.” Let’s begin by interpreting this
to mean that smaller government tends either to produce greater human
prosperity as measured by Legatum’s LPI or greater human freedom as measured by
Cato’s HFI. Here are the relevant scatterplots, based on a sample of 143
countries, using SGOV, the IMF measure, for size of government:
The plots do not support the hypothesis that small
government produces either greater prosperity or greater freedom. (In reading
the charts, remember that the SGOV index is constructed so that 0 indicates the
largest government and 10 the smallest government.) Instead, smaller government
tends to be associated with less prosperity and less freedom. Both
relationships are statistically significant, with correlations of 0.43 for
prosperity and 0.35 for freedom.
Using SoG, the Cato measure of size of government, instead
of SGOV, the IMF measure, does not help. The correlations turn out still to be
negative and statistically significant, although slightly weaker.
Let’s turn now to the alternative hypothesis that quality of
government, rather than size, is what counts for prosperity and freedom. Here
are those scatterplots:
This time, both relationships are positive. High quality of
government is strongly associated both with greater human prosperity and
greater human freedom. Furthermore, the correlations are much stronger than
those for the size of government.
But wait a minute. Before reaching any conclusions about the
relative importance of size and quality of government, shouldn’t we should look
at the relationship between those two variables? Could it be, for example, that
quality matters, but also be true that small governments tend to be high
quality governments? If so, then small government might still contribute to
prosperity and freedom, but in a way that is statistically masked when we plot
SGOV in isolation against either LPI or HFI.
However, that turns out that small governments do not, on
the whole, tend to be of better quality. Here is what we get when we plot
quality against size of government:
To help with interpretation, this figure ads labels to some
of the data points. The red lines divide the figure into quadrants according
the median values for size and quality of government. A trend line runs roughly
from France to Nigeria. The correlation is definitely negative: Smaller
governments (those to the right of the figure) tend to have lower quality. The relationship
between the two variables is statistically significant, with a correlation of
-0.48.
The governments with the highest quality scores are found among
those in the northwest quadrant – the largest governments as measured by
expenditures relative to GDP. It is no surprise to find a cluster of
Scandinavian countries there, with some of their fellow EU members not far
away. Farther to the right lie New Zealand and Switzerland (CHE), two countries
with well-run governments that are close to the median size. The US government
is also close to median size. Its quality score is a little lower, but still
well above the trend line. In the same quadrant, but below the trend line—large
but lower-quality governments—we find Kuwait and Saudi Arabia. Some of the
other Gulf States are in the same neighborhood.
The northeast quadrant is more sparsely populated. The
outliers here are Singapore and Hong Kong, countries with governments that are
well run, but small in terms of expenditures. South Korea also falls into this
quadrant, as does Ireland, which has a high-quality government that is
relatively small by EU standards.
Moving to the southeast quadrant, we find countries that
have small but low-quality governments, such as Nigeria, Democratic Republic of
Congo, Chad, Central African Republic, Bangladesh, and others. These countries
are also among the poorest on the planet in terms of per-capita GDP and indicators
of human flourishing.
Finally, in the southwest quadrant, we find the sorry
example of Venezuela – this decade’s poster child for socialism gone bad. North
Korea would probably be nearby, but we don’t have enough data to include it in
the sample. Russia and China are also in this quadrant, but much closer to the
center, with both size and quality of government close to the median.
We conclude, then, that the hypothesis, “That government is
best which governs least,” does not hold up well. The data suggest that
Thoreau’s axiom should read, “That government is best which governs well.”
In short, quality of government, not size of government, is
what matters for freedom and prosperity.
This post originally appeared in this form on Medium. For more details on
data and methodology, read this two-part series: “Freedom,
Prosperity, and Big Government,” and “Quality
of Government, Not Size, Is the Key to Freedom and Prosperity.”
No comments:
Post a Comment