As the stock market soars to one record high after another, analysts
do not hesitate to tell us why. One popular explanation is that expectations of
higher interest rates are pushing up the stocks of banks and other financial
companies (example). Yet
not so long ago, the same analysts were telling us that Wall Street in general
and banks in particular were getting rich on the “free money” that the Fed was
supplying to them at historically low
rates (examples here
and here).
What gives?
To understand how interest rates affect bank profits, we turn
to a wonky concept of financial economics known as the duration gap. Setting the precise mathematics to one side (read
this if you really care), the duration gap refers to the difference between
the maturity of a bank’s assets and its liabilities. If a bank funds itself
with from short-term sources like deposits and uses those funds to make fixed
rate mortgage loans or buy long-term bonds, then it has a positive duration
gap. Interest rates tend to be higher on long-term financial instruments than
on those with short maturities, so is the way banks traditionally made a
profit.
The downside of the traditional banking model is that a positive
duration gap means that profits fall when interest rates rise. Suppose, for example, that your bank makes 30-year
fixed-rate mortgages and funds them with deposits that pay an interest equal to
the federal funds rate (the rate on overnight loans that the Fed uses at its
primary interest rate target). If the loans earn 4 percent and the fed funds
rate is 0.5 percent, you have a nice spread of 3.5 percent between return on assets and cost of funds, allowing
a good profit even after deducting operating
expenses. However, if short-term rates
went up, your bank would be in trouble. If the fed funds rate went up to 2
percent while your old fixed-rate mortgages still brought in just 4 percent
your spread would be cut to 1.5 percent and your profits, after operating
expenses, might evaporate altogether.
Modern banks have ways to reduce the interest rate risk
inherent in traditional banking. One of the simplest strategies is to make
variable-interest loans. If your funds come from short-term deposits, forget fixed-rate
mortgages. Instead, make loans with rates that reset every twelve months
according the movement of the federal funds rate or some other short-term interest
rate. Suppose that today, you are receiving 3.5 percent on your variable rate
mortgages (a little less than if you would earn
on fixed rate loans), and you are paying 0.5 percent on deposits.
Tomorrow, short-term rates go up and you have to raise your deposit rate to 2
percent, but you also reset the mortgage rate to 5 percent. Same 3 percent
spread, same profit, as before.
More complex strategies make it possible for banks even to engineer
negative duration gaps while still maintaining their traditional business of
taking in deposits and making loans. A bank with a negative duration gap would profit
from rising rates and suffer a loss if rates fell.
You get the idea: Banks do not have to passively accept
lower profits when interest rates rise and wait for falling rates to boost
their profits. Instead, they can adjust their strategies according to their
market expectations and their appetite for risk.
A cautious bank would try to keep its duration gap short. Such
a bank would earn a modest but steady profit regardless of what happened to
rates.
Banks with a bigger appetite for risk can try to guess which
way rates are moving. When they expect rates to go up, they can keep their gap
short, or even negative gap. When they expect rates to fall, they can make lots
of long-term, fixed-rate loans or use other strategies that lengthen the gap. If they turn out to be right, they win big.
If they are wrong, they suffer losses.
There is an important qualification, however. Trying to
profit from interest rate movements depends not only on the accuracy of forecasts,
but also on timing. For example, suppose I think that interest rates will fall.
If they do, prices of long-term bonds will rise, since bond prices
automatically move in the opposite direction from interest rates. If I am the
first to act on this expectation, I can buy bonds cheap now, while rates are still
low, and sell them at a higher price after the rate change. However, if other
people already played the same hunch yesterday, the purchases they made to lock
in their profits will already have pushed bond prices up, and I will have
missed my chance.
In short, then, there is no reason to think that bank
profits in general will increase either when interest rates rise, or when they
fall. Cautious banks that keep their duration gaps short will not be much
affected way or the other by rate changes. Banks that take risks based on their
guesses about interest rate movements will make profits but only if their
guesses are better than the average of others who are playing the same game. Since Wall Street is not Lake Wobegon, not all
banks can do better than average. Some will necessarily do worse than average,
and their losses will offset the gains made by the winners.
The moral of the story: Take tidy explanations of stock
price movements with a large grain of salt.
Originally posted at Economonitor.com
Except they don't have to do better than average bank, only better than average market with the market consisting of many other businesses and individuals.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDelete