The Wall
Street Journal reports that automakers are asking the EPA to repeal
automobile fuel economy standards, known as Corporate Average Fleet Economy
(CAFE) standards, which are set to rise to 56 miles per gallon by 2025.
Repealing the standards would be a good idea, provided they were replaced by
tax designed to achieve an equivalent saving in fuel. A carbon tax would do the
job nicely, but an increase in the existing tax on motor fuels would also work.
What, exactly, is
wrong with the CAFE standards? The fundamental problem is that they attack the third-party
effects, or negative externalities,
of motor fuel use, such as pollution, highway congestion, and accidents, only
partially and indirectly. As a result, the cost of achieving a given reduction
in fuel use via CAFE standards is higher than it would be if the same result
were achieved more directly through a carbon tax or an increase in the federal
gasoline tax.
To understand
why, we need to consider the various ways consumers can cut back on fuel use.
In the short run, they can buy an efficient hybrid instead of a gas-guzzling
SUV, they can reduce discretionary driving, or they can shift some trips from
their Ford F-250 to their Honda, if they happen to have one of each in the
driveway. Given more time to adjust, they can make work and lifestyle changes
like moving closer to public transportation, work and shopping, changing jobs,
or working at home.
The problem with
higher CAFE standards is that they encourage fuel saving only with regard to
the choice of what car to buy. Once a consumer buys a low-mileage vehicle, the
cost of driving and extra mile goes down, thereby reducing the incentive for
fuel-saving measures like moving closer to work, working at home, riding the
bus to work, or consolidating errands.
Economists refer
to the tendency of more fuel-efficient vehicles to induce additional driving as
the rebound effect. For example, suppose that a 10% increase in fuel efficiency
would cause a 3 percent increase in driving. The increased miles driven would
partly offset the increase in miles per gallon, so that total fuel consumption
would decrease by only about 7%.
To the extent
that externalities are proportion to the quantities of fuel consumed, as they
are in the case of air pollution, higher CAFE standards are still somewhat
helpful. However, the rebound effect causes an absolute increase in those
externalities that are proportional to miles driven, including road congestion
and traffic accidents. They also increases the cost of road maintenance,
because the wear and tear from more miles driven is only partly offset by the
lower average weight of high-mileage vehicles.
The very
fuel-saving strategies that CAFE standards discourage, like moving closer to
work or consolidating errands, are often the ones that have the lowest costs.
That is why the total cost of reaching a given national fuel-saving target will
be greater when achieved through CAFE standards than when induced by an
increase in fuel taxes. A 2004 study from the Congressional Budget Office concluded
that an increase in the federal gasoline tax would achieve a given reduction in
fuel economy at a cost 27 percent less than that of an equivalent tightening of
CAFE standards. Furthermore, its effects would be felt more quickly, because
they would not have to wait for the gradual turnover of the national motor
vehicle fleet. Over the 14-year time horizon of the CBO study, the gas tax
increase would save 42 percent more total fuel.
A 2013 study by Valerie J.
Karplus and colleagues of MIT found an even more dramatic difference. That
study estimated that achieving a given fuel savings through CAFE standards
would cost six to fourteen times more than achieving the same result through an
increase in fuel prices.
The variable most
critical to the size of the rebound effect, and therefore to the relative
merits of CAFE standards vs. fuel taxes, is the price-elasticity of demand for
fuel, that is, the percentage reduction in fuel use for each one percent
increase in fuel price. The less elastic is demand, the stronger is the case
for CAFE standards; the more elastic, the larger the rebound effect and the
stronger the case for raising fuel taxes.
What do we know
about price elasticity? A widely cited study by Molly
Espey of the University of Nevada concluded that the best estimate for the
price elasticity of gasoline demand was -0.26 in the short run and -0.58 in the
long run. Those estimates strongly undermine the case for CAFE standards.
A more
recent study by Todd Litman of the Victoria Transport Policy Institute
estimated long-run fuel price elasticities to be in a range of -0.4 to -0.8.
To be sure, not
everyone will be convinced by elasticity studies. They are just numbers. Some
people will continue to believe that prices have no effect on driving behavior,
that people will just drive whatever and wherever they want regardless. Here is
a picture, then, that is worth a thousand meta-analyses. Taken from the Litman
study cited above, it shows a convincingly tight relationship between fuel
prices and fuel use across OECD countries. Can it really be just coincidence
that the United States, with the lowest fuel prices, also has the highest fuel
consumption?
All this leaves
one last question. If CAFE standards are such a bad idea, why do they remain so
popular? If you are an economist, choosing higher fuel taxes over CAFE
standards looks like a no-brainer, but if you are a politician, fuel taxes have
an obvious drawback. Fuel taxes make the cost of reducing consumption highly
visible. You see the big dollars-per-gallon number right there in front of you
every time you drive up to the pump. CAFE standards, in contrast, hide the
cost. You pay the price of a higher-mileage car only when you buy a new one,
and even then, the part of the price attributable to the mileage-enhancing
features is not broken out as a separate item on the sticker. You may notice
that your new car costs more than your old one did, but there are lots of other
reasons for that besides fuel economy.
It is a classic case
of the TANSTAAFL
principle—There Ain't No Such Thing As A Free Lunch. If you try to make
something look like it’s free, it only ends up costing more in the long run. If
you are a politician, you may well prefer a big hidden cost to a small visible
cost. If you're a friend of the environment, you should know better.
The above includes updated passages from this
earlier post on CAFE standards.
No comments:
Post a Comment