“As President,” says candidate Rand Paul,
“I will work to authorize common sense solutions that will solve our
nation's fiscal crisis.” He has floated a broad proposal for a
constitutional amendment that would require the federal government to
balance its budget. Soon he will need to start filling in the specifics.
Here are some ideas that would combine common sense and fiscal prudence
while remaining true to Paul’s libertarian principles.
Toward a Libertarian Fiscal Policy
Rand
Paul is no anarcho-capitalist. He sees a legitimate, but limited, role
for government in national defense, law enforcement, the justice system,
and certain other areas. As Ralph Benko notes in a recent Forbes
article, that places him in the classical liberal wing of the
libertarian movement. With the option of zero government off the table,
the remaining minimal state must raise revenue and spend it. A
libertarian of classical liberal inclinations cannot get along without
some kind of fiscal policy, so what should it look like?
The first
principle should be, “Do no harm.” In a medical context, that precept
will be familiar to a physician like Senator Paul. In economics, “do no
harm” means a policy of fiscal neutrality—one of managing both
the revenue and spending sides of the budget in a way that disrupts the
functioning of the market economy as little as possible.
Unfortunately,
many past Republican proposals for budget balancing do not meet the
standard of fiscal neutrality. Take, for example, the balanced budget
amendment proposed not long ago by Utah Senators Orin Hatch and Mike
Lee. As I discussed in an earlier post,
that proposal, and others that would require the federal budget to be
exactly balanced each year, would be the opposite of neutral.
Because
tax revenue falls when the economy contracts, a rule like Hatch-Lee
would mandate sharp cuts in spending or increases in taxes each time the
economy entered a recession. Those measures would deepen the slump and
prolong the recovery. Even worse, from a libertarian perspective, they
would provide little or no restraint on spending when tax revenues rose
in good times. Lobbyists would descend on Washington like locusts, full
of ideas on how to spend the surplus. In short, requiring strict annual
balance for the current budget is anything but common sense. >>>Read more
Pages
▼
Thursday, April 16, 2015
Wednesday, April 8, 2015
UK Election: Did Austerity Work? This Chart Casts Doubt on the Claim
The general election campaign is in full swing in Britain, and it seems it’s all about austerity. From London, The New York Times reports that the
campaign revolves around a single issue: the economy, and whether its
rebound is the result of an austerity policy championed by the
Conservative-led government of David Cameron, or in spite of it.
When in doubt, we should let the facts speak for themselves. This chart tells it all:
The points in the chart represent thirty of the high-income democracies that comprise the OECD. It covers the years 2010-2014, the Cameron government’s term in office. The vertical axis shows the average annual rate of growth during the period. The horizontal axis shows the degree of austerity, or fiscal consolidation, as economists prefer to call it, applied in each country. The UK is right in the middle, just slightly below average in terms both of austerity and growth. >>>Read more
When in doubt, we should let the facts speak for themselves. This chart tells it all:
The points in the chart represent thirty of the high-income democracies that comprise the OECD. It covers the years 2010-2014, the Cameron government’s term in office. The vertical axis shows the average annual rate of growth during the period. The horizontal axis shows the degree of austerity, or fiscal consolidation, as economists prefer to call it, applied in each country. The UK is right in the middle, just slightly below average in terms both of austerity and growth. >>>Read more
Wednesday, April 1, 2015
What ShadowStats Gets Right and What it Gets Wrong
It is hard to think of a website so loved by its followers and so scorned by economists as John Williams' ShadowStats,
a widely cited source of alternative economic data on inflation and
other economic indicators. Any econ blogger who has ever written a line
about inflation is familiar with ShadowStats. Time and again, readers
cite it in comments, not infrequently paranoid in their tone and rude in
their language.
Brief replies that cast doubt on some of more extreme claims made by ShadowStats fans don’t seem to have much effect. After a recent round of comments, I promised the editor of one website to undertake a thorough deconstruction of ShadownStats. Here is the result.
What ShadowStats Gets Right: The CPI is a Flawed Measure of the Cost of Living
ShadowStats is Williams’ attempt to provide an alternative to the official consumer price index (CPI), which he views as a flawed measure of what members of the general public have in mind when they think of the cost of living. Let me start by saying that although I share the skepticism of many economists about the specific numbers published on ShadowStats, I agree that the official data do not tell the whole story. I support Williams’ attempt to provide an alternative to the official consumer price index that more closely reflects pubic perceptions of inflation. Here, in his own words, is how Williams explains his undertaking:
Brief replies that cast doubt on some of more extreme claims made by ShadowStats fans don’t seem to have much effect. After a recent round of comments, I promised the editor of one website to undertake a thorough deconstruction of ShadownStats. Here is the result.
What ShadowStats Gets Right: The CPI is a Flawed Measure of the Cost of Living
ShadowStats is Williams’ attempt to provide an alternative to the official consumer price index (CPI), which he views as a flawed measure of what members of the general public have in mind when they think of the cost of living. Let me start by saying that although I share the skepticism of many economists about the specific numbers published on ShadowStats, I agree that the official data do not tell the whole story. I support Williams’ attempt to provide an alternative to the official consumer price index that more closely reflects pubic perceptions of inflation. Here, in his own words, is how Williams explains his undertaking: